Le "Conclusioni in diritto" del giudice
Thomas Penfield Jackson
06.04.2000
UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA
|
) |
|
|
) |
|
UNITED STATES OF AMERICA, |
) |
|
|
) |
|
Plaintiff, |
) |
|
|
) |
|
v. |
) |
Civil Action No. 98-1232 (TPJ) |
|
) |
|
MICROSOFT CORPORATION, |
) |
|
|
) |
|
Defendant. |
) |
|
|
) |
|
|
|
|
STATE OF NEW YORK, et al., |
) |
|
|
) |
|
Plaintiffs |
) |
|
|
) |
|
v. |
) |
|
|
) |
|
MICROSOFT CORPORATION, |
) |
|
|
) |
|
Defendant |
) |
Civil Action No. 98-1233 (TPJ) |
|
) |
|
|
) |
|
|
) |
|
MICROSOFT CORPORATION, |
) |
|
|
) |
|
v. |
) |
|
|
) |
|
Counterclaim-Plaintiff, |
) |
|
|
) |
|
ELLIOT SPITZER, attorney |
) |
|
general of the State of |
) |
|
New York, in his official |
) |
|
capacity, et al., |
) |
|
|
) |
|
Counterclaim-Defendants. |
) |
|
|
) |
|
|
|
|
CONCLUSIONS OF LAW
The United States, nineteen
individual states, and the District of Columbia ("the plaintiffs")
bring these consolidated civil enforcement actions against defendant Microsoft
Corporation ("Microsoft") under the Sherman Antitrust Act, 15 U.S.C.
§§ 1 and 2. The plaintiffs charge, in essence, that Microsoft has waged an
unlawful campaign in defense of its monopoly position in the market for
operating systems designed to run on Intel-compatible personal computers ("PCs").
Specifically, the plaintiffs contend that Microsoft violated §2 of the Sherman
Act by engaging in a series of exclusionary, anticompetitive, and predatory acts
to maintain its monopoly power. They also assert that Microsoft attempted,
albeit unsuccessfully to date, to monopolize the Web browser market, likewise in
violation of §2. Finally, they contend that certain steps taken by Microsoft as
part of its campaign to protect its monopoly power, namely tying its browser to
its operating system and entering into exclusive dealing arrangements, violated
§ 1 of the Act.
Upon consideration of the Court's
Findings of Fact ("Findings"), filed herein on November 5, 1999, as
amended on December 21, 1999, the proposed conclusions of law submitted by the
parties, the briefs of amici curiae, and the argument of counsel
thereon, the Court concludes that Microsoft maintained its monopoly power by
anticompetitive means and attempted to monopolize the Web browser market, both
in violation of § 2. Microsoft also violated § 1 of the Sherman Act by
unlawfully tying its Web browser to its operating system. The facts found do not
support the conclusion, however, that the effect of Microsoft's marketing
arrangements with other companies constituted unlawful exclusive dealing under
criteria established by leading decisions under § 1.
The nineteen states and the District
of Columbia ("the plaintiff states") seek to ground liability
additionally under their respective antitrust laws. The Court is persuaded that
the evidence in the record proving violations of the Sherman Act also satisfies
the elements of analogous causes of action arising under the laws of each
plaintiff state. For this reason, and for others stated below, the Court holds
Microsoft liable under those particular state laws as well.
I. SECTION TWO OF THE SHERMAN ACT
A. Maintenance of Monopoly Power by
Anticompetitive Means
Section 2 of the Sherman Act declares that it is
unlawful for a person or firm to "monopolize . . . any part of the trade or
commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations . . . ." 15
U.S.C. § 2. This language operates to limit the means by which a firm may
lawfully either acquire or perpetuate monopoly power. Specifically, a firm
violates § 2 if it attains or preserves monopoly power through anticompetitive
acts. See United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 570-71
(1966) ("The offense of monopoly power under § 2 of the Sherman Act has
two elements: (1) the possession of monopoly power in the relevant market and
(2) the willful acquisition or maintenance of that power as distinguished from
growth or development as a consequence of a superior product, business acumen,
or historic accident."); Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services,
Inc., 504 U.S. 451, 488 (1992) (Scalia, J., dissenting) ("Our § 2
monopolization doctrines are . . . directed to discrete situations in which a
defendant's possession of substantial market power, combined with his
exclusionary or anticompetitive behavior, threatens to defeat or forestall the
corrective forces of competition and thereby sustain or extend the defendant's
agglomeration of power.").
1. Monopoly Power
The threshold element of a § 2 monopolization
offense being "the possession of monopoly power in the relevant
market," Grinnell, 384 U.S. at 570, the Court must first ascertain
the boundaries of the commercial activity that can be termed the "relevant
market." See Walker Process Equip., Inc. v. Food Mach. & Chem.
Corp., 382 U.S. 172, 177 (1965) ("Without a definition of [the relevant]
market there is no way to measure [defendant's] ability to lessen or destroy
competition."). Next, the Court must assess the defendant's actual power to
control prices in - or to exclude competition from - that market. See United
States v. E. I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 391 (1956)
("Monopoly power is the power to control prices or exclude competition.").
In this case, the plaintiffs postulated the
relevant market as being the worldwide licensing of Intel-compatible PC
operating systems. Whether this zone of commercial activity actually qualifies
as a market, "monopolization of which may be illegal," depends on
whether it includes all products "reasonably interchangeable by consumers
for the same purposes." du Pont, 351 U.S. at 395. See Rothery
Storage & Van Co. v. Atlas Van Lines, Inc., 792 F.2d 210, 218 (D.C. Cir.
1986) ("Because the ability of consumers to turn to other suppliers
restrains a firm from raising prices above the competitive level, the definition
of the 'relevant market' rests on a determination of available substitutes.").
The Court has already found, based on the
evidence in this record, that there are currently no products - and that there
are not likely to be any in the near future - that a significant percentage of
computer users worldwide could substitute for Intel-compatible PC operating
systems without incurring substantial costs. Findings ¶¶ 18-29. The Court has
further found that no firm not currently marketing Intel-compatible PC operating
systems could start doing so in a way that would, within a reasonably short
period of time, present a significant percentage of such consumers with a viable
alternative to existing Intel-compatible PC operating systems. Id. ¶¶
18, 30-32. From these facts, the Court has inferred that if a single firm or
cartel controlled the licensing of all Intel-compatible PC operating systems
worldwide, it could set the price of a license substantially above that which
would be charged in a competitive market - and leave the price there for a
significant period of time - without losing so many customers as to make the
action unprofitable. Id. ¶ 18. This inference, in turn, has led the
Court to find that the licensing of all Intel-compatible PC operating systems
worldwide does in fact constitute the relevant market in the context of the
plaintiffs' monopoly maintenance claim. Id.
The plaintiffs proved at trial that Microsoft
possesses a dominant, persistent, and increasing share of the relevant market.
Microsoft's share of the worldwide market for Intel-compatible PC operating
systems currently exceeds ninety-five percent, and the firm's share would stand
well above eighty percent even if the Mac OS were included in the market. Id.
¶ 35. The plaintiffs also proved that the applications barrier to entry
protects Microsoft's dominant market share. Id. ¶¶ 36-52. This barrier
ensures that no Intel-compatible PC operating system other than Windows can
attract significant consumer demand, and the barrier would operate to the same
effect even if Microsoft held its prices substantially above the competitive
level for a protracted period of time. Id. Together, the proof of
dominant market share and the existence of a substantial barrier to effective
entry create the presumption that Microsoft enjoys monopoly power. See United
States v. AT&T Co., 524 F. Supp. 1336, 1347-48 (D.D.C. 1981) ("a
persuasive showing . . . that defendants have monopoly power . . . through
various barriers to entry, . . . in combination with the evidence of market
shares, suffice[s] at least to meet the government's initial burden, and the
burden is then appropriately placed upon defendants to rebut the existence and
significance of barriers to entry"), quoted with approval in Southern
Pac. Communications Co. v. AT&T Co., 740 F.2d 980, 1001-02 (D.C. Cir.
1984).
At trial, Microsoft attempted to rebut the
presumption of monopoly power with evidence of both putative constraints on its
ability to exercise such power and behavior of its own that is supposedly
inconsistent with the possession of monopoly power. None of the purported
constraints, however, actually deprive Microsoft of "the ability (1) to
price substantially above the competitive level and (2) to persist in
doing so for a significant period without erosion by new entry or expansion."
IIA Phillip E. Areeda, Herbert Hovenkamp & John L. Solow, Antitrust Law ¶
501, at 86 (1995) (emphasis in original); see Findings ¶¶ 57-60.
Furthermore, neither Microsoft's efforts at technical innovation nor its pricing
behavior is inconsistent with the possession of monopoly power. Id. ¶¶
61-66.
Even if Microsoft's rebuttal had attenuated the
presumption created by the prima facie showing of monopoly power,
corroborative evidence of monopoly power abounds in this record: Neither
Microsoft nor its OEM customers believe that the latter have - or will have
anytime soon - even a single, commercially viable alternative to licensing
Windows for pre-installation on their PCs. Id. ¶¶ 53-55; cf. Rothery,
792 F.2d at 219 n.4 ("we assume that economic actors usually have accurate
perceptions of economic realities"). Moreover, over the past several years,
Microsoft has comported itself in a way that could only be consistent with
rational behavior for a profit-maximizing firm if the firm knew that it
possessed monopoly power, and if it was motivated by a desire to preserve the
barrier to entry protecting that power. Findings ¶¶ 67, 99, 136, 141, 215-16,
241, 261-62, 286, 291, 330, 355, 393, 407.
In short, the proof of Microsoft's dominant,
persistent market share protected by a substantial barrier to entry, together
with Microsoft's failure to rebut that prima facie showing
effectively and the additional indicia of monopoly power, have compelled the
Court to find as fact that Microsoft enjoys monopoly power in the relevant
market. Id. ¶ 33.
2. Maintenance of Monopoly Power by
Anticompetitive Means
In a § 2 case, once it is proved that the
defendant possesses monopoly power in a relevant market, liability for
monopolization depends on a showing that the defendant used anticompetitive
methods to achieve or maintain its position. See United States v.
Grinnell, 384 U.S. 563, 570-71 (1966); Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image
Technical Services, Inc., 504 U.S. 451, 488 (1992) (Scalia, J., dissenting);
Intergraph Corp. v. Intel Corp., 195 F.3d 1346, 1353 (Fed. Cir. 1999).
Prior cases have established an analytical approach to determining whether
challenged conduct should be deemed anticompetitive in the context of a monopoly
maintenance claim. The threshold question in this analysis is whether the
defendant's conduct is "exclusionary" - that is, whether it has
restricted significantly, or threatens to restrict significantly, the ability of
other firms to compete in the relevant market on the merits of what they offer
customers. See Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S. at 488 (Scalia, J.,
dissenting) (§ 2 is "directed to discrete situations" in which the
behavior of firms with monopoly power "threatens to defeat or forestall the
corrective forces of competition").(1)
If the evidence reveals a significant
exclusionary impact in the relevant market, the defendant's conduct will be
labeled "anticompetitive" - and liability will attach - unless the
defendant comes forward with specific, procompetitive business motivations that
explain the full extent of its exclusionary conduct. See Eastman Kodak,
504 U.S. at 483 (declining to grant defendant's motion for summary judgment
because factual questions remained as to whether defendant's asserted
justifications were sufficient to explain the exclusionary conduct or were
instead merely pretextual); see also Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen
Highlands Skiing Corp., 472 U.S. 585, 605 n.32 (1985) (holding that the
second element of a monopoly maintenance claim is satisfied by proof of "'behavior
that not only (1) tends to impair the opportunities of rivals, but also (2)
either does not further competition on the merits or does so in an unnecessarily
restrictive way'") (quoting III Phillip E. Areeda & Donald F. Turner, Antitrust
Law ¶ 626b, at 78 (1978)).
If the defendant with monopoly power consciously
antagonized its customers by making its products less attractive to them - or if
it incurred other costs, such as large outlays of development capital and
forfeited opportunities to derive revenue from it - with no prospect of
compensation other than the erection or preservation of barriers against
competition by equally efficient firms, the Court may deem the defendant's
conduct "predatory." As the D.C. Circuit stated in Neumann v.
Reinforced Earth Co.,
[P]redation involves aggression against business
rivals through the use of business practices that would not be considered profit
maximizing except for the expectation that (1) actual rivals will be driven from
the market, or the entry of potential rivals blocked or delayed, so that the
predator will gain or retain a market share sufficient to command monopoly
profits, or (2) rivals will be chastened sufficiently to abandon competitive
behavior the predator finds threatening to its realization of monopoly profits.
786 F.2d 424, 427 (D.C. Cir. 1986).
Proof that a profit-maximizing firm took
predatory action should suffice to demonstrate the threat of substantial
exclusionary effect; to hold otherwise would be to ascribe irrational behavior
to the defendant. Moreover, predatory conduct, by definition as well as by
nature, lacks procompetitive business motivation. See Aspen Skiing,
472 U.S. at 610-11 (evidence indicating that defendant's conduct was "motivated
entirely by a decision to avoid providing any benefits" to a rival
supported the inference that defendant's conduct "was not motivated by
efficiency concerns"). In other words, predatory behavior is patently
anticompetitive. Proof that a firm with monopoly power engaged in such behavior
thus necessitates a finding of liability under § 2.
In this case, Microsoft early on recognized
middleware as the Trojan horse that, once having, in effect, infiltrated the
applications barrier, could enable rival operating systems to enter the market
for Intel-compatible PC operating systems unimpeded. Simply put, middleware
threatened to demolish Microsoft's coveted monopoly power. Alerted to the threat,
Microsoft strove over a period of approximately four years to prevent middleware
technologies from fostering the development of enough full-featured,
cross-platform applications to erode the applications barrier. In pursuit of
this goal, Microsoft sought to convince developers to concentrate on
Windows-specific APIs and ignore interfaces exposed by the two incarnations of
middleware that posed the greatest threat, namely, Netscape's Navigator Web
browser and Sun's implementation of the Java technology. Microsoft's campaign
succeeded in preventing - for several years, and perhaps permanently - Navigator
and Java from fulfilling their potential to open the market for Intel-compatible
PC operating systems to competition on the merits. Findings ¶¶ 133, 378.
Because Microsoft achieved this result through exclusionary acts that lacked
procompetitive justification, the Court deems Microsoft's conduct the
maintenance of monopoly power by anticompetitive means.
a. Combating the Browser Threat
The same ambition that inspired Microsoft's
efforts to induce Intel, Apple, RealNetworks and IBM to desist from certain
technological innovations and business initiatives - namely, the desire to
preserve the applications barrier - motivated the firm's June 1995 proposal that
Netscape abstain from releasing platform-level browsing software for 32-bit
versions of Windows. See id. ¶¶ 79-80, 93-132. This proposal,
together with the punitive measures that Microsoft inflicted on Netscape when it
rebuffed the overture, illuminates the context in which Microsoft's subsequent
behavior toward PC manufacturers ("OEMs"), Internet access providers
("IAPs"), and other firms must be viewed.
When Netscape refused to abandon its efforts to
develop Navigator into a substantial platform for applications development,
Microsoft focused its efforts on minimizing the extent to which developers would
avail themselves of interfaces exposed by that nascent platform. Microsoft
realized that the extent of developers' reliance on Netscape's browser platform
would depend largely on the size and trajectory of Navigator's share of browser
usage. Microsoft thus set out to maximize Internet Explorer's share of browser
usage at Navigator's expense. Id. ¶¶ 133, 359-61. The core of this
strategy was ensuring that the firms comprising the most effective channels for
the generation of browser usage would devote their distributional and
promotional efforts to Internet Explorer rather than Navigator. Recognizing that
pre-installation by OEMs and bundling with the proprietary software of IAPs led
more directly and efficiently to browser usage than any other practices in the
industry, Microsoft devoted major efforts to usurping those two channels. Id.
¶ 143.
i. The OEM Channel
With respect to OEMs, Microsoft's campaign
proceeded on three fronts. First, Microsoft bound Internet Explorer to Windows
with contractual and, later, technological shackles in order to ensure the
prominent (and ultimately permanent) presence of Internet Explorer on every
Windows user's PC system, and to increase the costs attendant to installing and
using Navigator on any PCs running Windows. Id. ¶¶ 155-74. Second,
Microsoft imposed stringent limits on the freedom of OEMs to reconfigure or
modify Windows 95 and Windows 98 in ways that might enable OEMs to generate
usage for Navigator in spite of the contractual and technological devices that
Microsoft had employed to bind Internet Explorer to Windows. Id. ¶¶
202-29. Finally, Microsoft used incentives and threats to induce especially
important OEMs to design their distributional, promotional and technical efforts
to favor Internet Explorer to the exclusion of Navigator. Id. ¶¶
230-38.
Microsoft's actions increased the likelihood that
pre-installation of Navigator onto Windows would cause user confusion and system
degradation, and therefore lead to higher support costs and reduced sales for
the OEMs. Id. ¶¶ 159, 172. Not willing to take actions that would
jeopardize their already slender profit margins, OEMs felt compelled by
Microsoft's actions to reduce drastically their distribution and promotion of
Navigator. Id. ¶¶ 239, 241. The substantial inducements that Microsoft
held out to the largest OEMs only further reduced the distribution and promotion
of Navigator in the OEM channel. Id. ¶¶ 230, 233. The response of OEMs
to Microsoft's efforts had a dramatic, negative impact on Navigator's usage
share. Id. ¶ 376. The drop in usage share, in turn, has prevented
Navigator from being the vehicle to open the relevant market to competition on
the merits. Id. ¶¶ 377-78, 383.
Microsoft fails to advance any legitimate
business objectives that actually explain the full extent of this significant
exclusionary impact. The Court has already found that no quality-related or
technical justifications fully explain Microsoft's refusal to license Windows 95
to OEMs without version 1.0 through 4.0 of Internet Explorer, or its refusal to
permit them to uninstall versions 3.0 and 4.0. Id. ¶¶ 175-76. The same
lack of justification applies to Microsoft's decision not to offer a browserless
version of Windows 98 to consumers and OEMs, id. ¶ 177, as well as to
its claim that it could offer "best of breed" implementations of
functionalities in Web browsers. With respect to the latter assertion, Internet
Explorer is not demonstrably the current "best of breed" Web browser,
nor is it likely to be so at any time in the immediate future. The fact that
Microsoft itself was aware of this reality only further strengthens the
conclusion that Microsoft's decision to tie Internet Explorer to Windows cannot
truly be explained as an attempt to benefit consumers and improve the efficiency
of the software market generally, but rather as part of a larger campaign to
quash innovation that threatened its monopoly position. Id. ¶¶ 195,
198.
To the extent that Microsoft still asserts a
copyright defense, relying upon federal copyright law as a justification for its
various restrictions on OEMs, that defense neither explains nor operates to
immunize Microsoft's conduct under the Sherman Act. As a general proposition,
Microsoft argues that the federal Copyright Act, 17 U.S.C. §101 et seq.,
endows the holder of a valid copyright in software with an absolute right to
prevent licensees, in this case the OEMs, from shipping modified versions of its
product without its express permission. In truth, Windows 95 and Windows 98 are
covered by copyright registrations, Findings ¶ 228, that "constitute prima
facie evidence of the validity of the copyright." 17 U.S.C.
§410(c). But the validity of Microsoft's copyrights has never been in
doubt; the issue is what, precisely, they protect.
Microsoft has presented no evidence that the
contractual (or the technological) restrictions it placed on OEMs' ability to
alter Windows derive from any of the enumerated rights explicitly granted to a
copyright holder under the Copyright Act. Instead, Microsoft argues that the
restrictions "simply restate" an expansive right to preserve the
"integrity"of its copyrighted software against any "distortion,"
"truncation," or "alteration," a right nowhere mentioned
among the Copyright Act's list of exclusive rights, 17 U.S.C. §106, thus
raising some doubt as to its existence. See Twentieth Century Music
Corp. v. Aiken, 422 U.S. 151, 155 (1973) (not all uses of a work are within
copyright holder's control; rights limited to specifically granted "exclusive
rights"); cf. 17 U.S.C. § 501(a) (infringement means violating
specifically enumerated rights).(2)
It is also well settled that a copyright holder
is not by reason thereof entitled to employ the perquisites in ways that
directly threaten competition. See, e.g., Eastman Kodak,
504 U.S. at 479 n.29 ("The Court has held many times that power gained
through some natural and legal advantage such as a . . . copyright, . . . can
give rise to liability if 'a seller exploits his dominant position in one market
to expand his empire into the next.'") (quoting Times-Picayune Pub. Co.
v. United States, 345 U.S. 594, 611 (1953)); Square D Co. v. Niagara
Frontier Tariff Bureau, Inc., 476 U.S. 409, 421 (1986); Data General
Corp. v. Grumman Systems Support Corp., 36 F.3d 1147, 1186 n.63 (1st Cir.
1994) (a copyright does not exempt its holder from antitrust inquiry where the
copyright is used as part of a scheme to monopolize); see also Image
Technical Services, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 125 F.3d 1195, 1219 (9th Cir.
1997), cert. denied, 523 U.S. 1094 (1998) ("Neither the aims of
intellectual property law, nor the antitrust laws justify allowing a monopolist
to rely upon a pretextual business justification to mask anticompetitive
conduct."). Even constitutional privileges confer no immunity when they are
abused for anticompetitive purposes. See Lorain Journal Co. v. United
States, 342 U.S. 143, 155-56 (1951). The Court has already found that the
true impetus behind Microsoft's restrictions on OEMs was not its desire to
maintain a somewhat amorphous quality it refers to as the "integrity"
of the Windows platform, nor even to ensure that Windows afforded a uniform and
stable platform for applications development. Microsoft itself engendered, or at
least countenanced, instability and inconsistency by permitting
Microsoft-friendly modifications to the desktop and boot sequence, and by
releasing updates to Internet Explorer more frequently than it released new
versions of Windows. Findings ¶ 226. Add to this the fact that the
modifications OEMs desired to make would not have removed or altered any Windows
APIs, and thus would not have disrupted any of Windows' functionalities, and it
is apparent that Microsoft's conduct is effectively explained by its foreboding
that OEMs would pre-install and give prominent placement to middleware like
Navigator that could attract enough developer attention to weaken the
applications barrier to entry. Id. ¶ 227. In short, if Microsoft was
truly inspired by a genuine concern for maximizing consumer satisfaction, as
well as preserving its substantial investment in a worthy product, then it would
have relied more on the power of the very competitive PC market, and less on its
own market power, to prevent OEMs from making modifications that consumers did
not want. Id. ¶¶ 225, 228-29.
ii. The IAP Channel
Microsoft adopted similarly aggressive measures
to ensure that the IAP channel would generate browser usage share for Internet
Explorer rather than Navigator. To begin with, Microsoft licensed Internet
Explorer and the Internet Explorer Access Kit to hundreds of IAPs for no charge.
Id. ¶¶ 250-51. Then, Microsoft extended valuable promotional treatment
to the ten most important IAPs in exchange for their commitment to promote and
distribute Internet Explorer and to exile Navigator from the desktop. Id.
¶¶ 255-58, 261, 272, 288-90, 305-06. Finally, in exchange for efforts to
upgrade existing subscribers to client software that came bundled with Internet
Explorer instead of Navigator, Microsoft granted rebates - and in some cases
made outright payments - to those same IAPs. Id. ¶¶ 259-60, 295. Given
the importance of the IAP channel to browser usage share, it is fair to conclude
that these inducements and restrictions contributed significantly to the drastic
changes that have in fact occurred in Internet Explorer's and Navigator's
respective usage shares. Id. ¶¶ 144-47, 309-10. Microsoft's actions in
the IAP channel thereby contributed significantly to preserving the applications
barrier to entry.
There are no valid reasons to justify the full
extent of Microsoft's exclusionary behavior in the IAP channel. A desire to
limit free riding on the firm's investment in consumer-oriented features, such
as the Referral Server and the Online Services Folder, can, in some
circumstances, qualify as a procompetitive business motivation; but that
motivation does not explain the full extent of the restrictions that Microsoft
actually imposed upon IAPs. Under the terms of the agreements, an IAP's failure
to keep Navigator shipments below the specified percentage primed Microsoft's
contractual right to dismiss the IAP from its own favored position in the
Referral Server or the Online Services Folder. This was true even if the IAP had
refrained from promoting Navigator in its client software included with Windows,
had purged all mention of Navigator from any Web site directly connected to the
Referral Server, and had distributed no browser other than Internet Explorer to
the new subscribers it gleaned from the Windows desktop. Id. ¶¶ 258,
262, 289. Thus, Microsoft's restrictions closed off a substantial amount of
distribution that would not have constituted a free ride to Navigator.
Nor can an ostensibly procompetitive desire to
"foster brand association" explain the full extent of Microsoft's
restrictions. If Microsoft's only concern had been brand association,
restrictions on the ability of IAPs to promote Navigator likely would have
sufficed. It is doubtful that Microsoft would have paid IAPs to induce their
existing subscribers to drop Navigator in favor of Internet Explorer unless it
was motivated by a desire to extinguish Navigator as a threat. See id.
¶¶ 259, 295. More generally, it is crucial to an understanding of
Microsoft's intentions to recognize that Microsoft paid for the fealty of IAPs
with large investments in software development for their benefit, conceded
opportunities to take a profit, suffered competitive disadvantage to Microsoft's
own OLS, and gave outright bounties. Id. ¶¶ 259-60, 277, 284-86, 295.
Considering that Microsoft never intended to derive appreciable revenue from
Internet Explorer directly, id. ¶¶ 136-37, these sacrifices could only
have represented rational business judgments to the extent that they promised to
diminish Navigator's share of browser usage and thereby contribute significantly
to eliminating a threat to the applications barrier to entry. Id. ¶ 291.
Because the full extent of Microsoft's exclusionary initiatives in the IAP
channel can only be explained by the desire to hinder competition on the merits
in the relevant market, those initiatives must be labeled anticompetitive.
In sum, the efforts Microsoft directed at OEMs
and IAPs successfully ostracized Navigator as a practical matter from the two
channels that lead most efficiently to browser usage. Even when viewed
independently, these two prongs of Microsoft's campaign threatened to "forestall
the corrective forces of competition" and thereby perpetuate Microsoft's
monopoly power in the relevant market. Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical
Services, Inc., 504 U.S. 451, 488 (1992) (Scalia, J., dissenting). Therefore,
whether they are viewed separately or together, the OEM and IAP components of
Microsoft's anticompetitive campaign merit a finding of liability under § 2.
iii. ICPs, ISVs and Apple
No other distribution channels for browsing
software approach the efficiency of OEM pre-installation and IAP bundling.
Findings ¶¶ 144-47. Nevertheless, protecting the applications barrier to entry
was so critical to Microsoft that the firm was willing to invest substantial
resources to enlist ICPs, ISVs, and Apple in its campaign against the browser
threat. By extracting from Apple terms that significantly diminished the usage
of Navigator on the Mac OS, Microsoft helped to ensure that developers would not
view Navigator as truly cross-platform middleware. Id. ¶ 356. By
granting ICPs and ISVs free licenses to bundle Internet Explorer with their
offerings, and by exchanging other valuable inducements for their agreement to
distribute, promote and rely on Internet Explorer rather than Navigator,
Microsoft directly induced developers to focus on its own APIs rather than ones
exposed by Navigator. Id. ¶¶ 334-35, 340. These measures supplemented
Microsoft's efforts in the OEM and IAP channels.
Just as they fail to account for the measures
that Microsoft took in the IAP channel, the goals of preventing free riding and
preserving brand association fail to explain the full extent of Microsoft's
actions in the ICP channel. Id. ¶¶ 329-30. With respect to the ISV
agreements, Microsoft has put forward no procompetitive business ends whatsoever
to justify their exclusionary terms. See id. ¶¶ 339-40. Finally,
Microsoft's willingness to make the sacrifices involved in cancelling Mac
Office, and the concessions relating to browsing software that it demanded from
Apple, can only be explained by Microsoft's desire to protect the applications
barrier to entry from the threat posed by Navigator. Id. ¶ 355. Thus,
once again, Microsoft is unable to justify the full extent of its restrictive
behavior.
b. Combating the Java Threat
As part of its grand strategy to protect the
applications barrier, Microsoft employed an array of tactics designed to
maximize the difficulty with which applications written in Java could be ported
from Windows to other platforms, and vice versa. The first of
these measures was the creation of a Java implementation for Windows that
undermined portability and was incompatible with other implementations. Id.
¶¶ 387-93. Microsoft then induced developers to use its implementation of Java
rather than Sun-compliant ones. It pursued this tactic directly, by means of
subterfuge and barter, and indirectly, through its campaign to minimize
Navigator's usage share. Id. ¶¶ 394, 396-97, 399-400, 401-03. In a
separate effort to prevent the development of easily portable Java applications,
Microsoft used its monopoly power to prevent firms such as Intel from aiding in
the creation of cross-platform interfaces. Id. ¶¶ 404-06.
Microsoft's tactics induced many Java developers
to write their applications using Microsoft's developer tools and to refrain
from distributing Sun-compliant JVMs to Windows users. This stratagem has
effectively resulted in fewer applications that are easily portable. Id.
¶ 398. What is more, Microsoft's actions interfered with the development of new
cross-platform Java interfaces. Id. ¶ 406. It is not clear whether,
absent Microsoft's machinations, Sun's Java efforts would by now have
facilitated porting between Windows and other platforms to a degree sufficient
to render the applications barrier to entry vulnerable. It is clear, however,
that Microsoft's actions markedly impeded Java's progress to that end. Id.
¶ 407. The evidence thus compels the conclusion that Microsoft's actions with
respect to Java have restricted significantly the ability of other firms to
compete on the merits in the market for Intel-compatible PC operating systems.
Microsoft's actions to counter the Java threat
went far beyond the development of an attractive alternative to Sun's
implementation of the technology. Specifically, Microsoft successfully pressured
Intel, which was dependent in many ways on Microsoft's good graces, to abstain
from aiding in Sun's and Netscape's Java development work. Id. ¶¶ 396,
406. Microsoft also deliberately designed its Java development tools so that
developers who were opting for portability over performance would nevertheless
unwittingly write Java applications that would run only on Windows. Id.
¶ 394. Moreover, Microsoft's means of luring developers to its Java
implementation included maximizing Internet Explorer's share of browser usage at
Navigator's expense in ways the Court has already held to be anticompetitive. See
supra, § I.A.2.a. Finally, Microsoft impelled ISVs, which are dependent
upon Microsoft for technical information and certifications relating to Windows,
to use and distribute Microsoft's version of the Windows JVM rather than any
Sun-compliant version. Id. ¶¶ 401-03.
These actions cannot be described as competition
on the merits, and they did not benefit consumers. In fact, Microsoft's actions
did not even benefit Microsoft in the short run, for the firm's efforts to
create incompatibility between its JVM for Windows and others' JVMs for Windows
resulted in fewer total applications being able to run on Windows than otherwise
would have been written. Microsoft was willing nevertheless to obstruct the
development of Windows-compatible applications if they would be easy to port to
other platforms and would thus diminish the applications barrier to entry. Id.
¶ 407.
c. Microsoft's Conduct Taken As a Whole
As the foregoing discussion illustrates,
Microsoft's campaign to protect the applications barrier from erosion by
network-centric middleware can be broken down into discrete categories of
activity, several of which on their own independently satisfy the second element
of a § 2 monopoly maintenance claim. But only when the separate categories of
conduct are viewed, as they should be, as a single, well-coordinated course of
action does the full extent of the violence that Microsoft has done to the
competitive process reveal itself. See Continental Ore Co. v. Union
Carbide & Carbon Corp., 370 U.S. 690, 699 (1962) (counseling that in
Sherman Act cases "plaintiffs should be given the full benefit of their
proof without tightly compartmentalizing the various factual components and
wiping the slate clean after scrutiny of each"). In essence, Microsoft
mounted a deliberate assault upon entrepreneurial efforts that, left to rise or
fall on their own merits, could well have enabled the introduction of
competition into the market for Intel-compatible PC operating systems. Id.
¶ 411. While the evidence does not prove that they would have succeeded absent
Microsoft's actions, it does reveal that Microsoft placed an oppressive thumb on
the scale of competitive fortune, thereby effectively guaranteeing its continued
dominance in the relevant market. More broadly, Microsoft's anticompetitive
actions trammeled the competitive process through which the computer software
industry generally stimulates innovation and conduces to the optimum benefit of
consumers. Id. ¶ 412.
Viewing Microsoft's conduct as a whole also
reinforces the conviction that it was predacious. Microsoft paid vast sums of
money, and renounced many millions more in lost revenue every year, in order to
induce firms to take actions that would help enhance Internet Explorer's share
of browser usage at Navigator's expense. Id. ¶ 139. These outlays cannot
be explained as subventions to maximize return from Internet Explorer. Microsoft
has no intention of ever charging for licenses to use or distribute its browser.
Id. ¶¶ 137-38. Moreover, neither the desire to bolster demand for
Windows nor the prospect of ancillary revenues from Internet Explorer can
explain the lengths to which Microsoft has gone. In fact, Microsoft has expended
wealth and foresworn opportunities to realize more in a manner and to an extent
that can only represent a rational investment if its purpose was to perpetuate
the applications barrier to entry. Id. ¶¶ 136, 139-42. Because
Microsoft's business practices "would not be considered profit maximizing
except for the expectation that . . . the entry of potential rivals" into
the market for Intel-compatible PC operating systems will be "blocked or
delayed," Neumann v. Reinforced Earth Co., 786 F.2d 424, 427 (D.C.
Cir. 1986), Microsoft's campaign must be termed predatory. Since the Court has
already found that Microsoft possesses monopoly power, see supra,
§ I.A.1, the predatory nature of the firm's conduct compels the Court to hold
Microsoft liable under § 2 of the Sherman Act.
B. Attempting to Obtain Monopoly Power in a
Second Market by Anticompetitive Means
In addition to condemning actual monopolization,
§ 2 of the Sherman Act declares that it is unlawful for a person or firm to
"attempt to monopolize . . . any part of the trade or commerce among the
several States, or with foreign nations . . . ." 15 U.S.C. § 2. Relying on
this language, the plaintiffs assert that Microsoft's anticompetitive efforts to
maintain its monopoly power in the market for Intel-compatible PC operating
systems warrant additional liability as an illegal attempt to amass monopoly
power in "the browser market." The Court agrees.
In order for liability to attach for attempted
monopolization, a plaintiff generally must prove "(1) that the defendant
has engaged in predatory or anticompetitive conduct with (2) a specific intent
to monopolize," and (3) that there is a "dangerous probability"
that the defendant will succeed in achieving monopoly power. Spectrum Sports,
Inc. v. McQuillan, 506 U.S. 447, 456 (1993). Microsoft's June 1995 proposal
that Netscape abandon the field to Microsoft in the market for browsing
technology for Windows, and its subsequent, well-documented efforts to overwhelm
Navigator's browser usage share with a proliferation of Internet Explorer
browsers inextricably attached to Windows, clearly meet the first element of the
offense.
The evidence in this record also satisfies the
requirement of specific intent. Microsoft's effort to convince Netscape to stop
developing platform-level browsing software for the 32-bit versions of Windows
was made with full knowledge that Netscape's acquiescence in this market
allocation scheme would, without more, have left Internet Explorer with such a
large share of browser usage as to endow Microsoft with de facto
monopoly power in the browser market. Findings ¶¶ 79-89.
When Netscape refused to abandon the development
of browsing software for 32-bit versions of Windows, Microsoft's strategy for
protecting the applications barrier became one of expanding Internet Explorer's
share of browser usage - and simultaneously depressing Navigator's share - to an
extent sufficient to demonstrate to developers that Navigator would never emerge
as the standard software employed to browse the Web. Id. ¶ 133. While
Microsoft's top executives never expressly declared acquisition of monopoly
power in the browser market to be the objective, they knew, or should have known,
that the tactics they actually employed were likely to push Internet Explorer's
share to those extreme heights. Navigator's slow demise would leave a
competitive vacuum for only Internet Explorer to fill. Yet, there is no evidence
that Microsoft tried - or even considered trying - to prevent its
anticompetitive campaign from achieving overkill. Under these circumstances, it
is fair to presume that the wrongdoer intended "the probable consequences
of its acts." IIIA Phillip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust
Law ¶ 805b, at 324 (1996); see also Spectrum Sports,
506 U.S. at 459 (proof of "'predatory' tactics . . . may be sufficient to
prove the necessary intent to monopolize, which is something more than an intent
to compete vigorously"). Therefore, the facts of this case suffice to prove
the element of specific intent.
Even if the first two elements of the offense are
met, however, a defendant may not be held liable for attempted monopolization
absent proof that its anticompetitive conduct created a dangerous probability of
achieving the objective of monopoly power in a relevant market. Id. The
evidence supports the conclusion that Microsoft's actions did pose such a danger.
At the time Microsoft presented its market
allocation proposal to Netscape, Navigator's share of browser usage stood well
above seventy percent, and no other browser enjoyed more than a fraction of the
remainder. Findings ¶¶ 89, 372. Had Netscape accepted Microsoft's offer,
nearly all of its share would have devolved upon Microsoft, because at that
point, no potential third-party competitor could either claim to rival Netscape's
stature as a browser company or match Microsoft's ability to leverage monopoly
power in the market for Intel-compatible PC operating systems. In the time it
would have taken an aspiring entrant to launch a serious effort to compete
against Internet Explorer, Microsoft could have erected the same type of barrier
that protects its existing monopoly power by adding proprietary extensions to
the browsing software under its control and by extracting commitments from OEMs,
IAPs and others similar to the ones discussed in § I.A.2, supra. In
short, Netscape's assent to Microsoft's market division proposal would have, instanter,
resulted in Microsoft's attainment of monopoly power in a second market. It
follows that the proposal itself created a dangerous probability of that result.
See United States v. American Airlines, Inc., 743 F.2d 1114,
1118-19 (5th Cir. 1984) (fact that two executives "arguably" could
have implemented market-allocation scheme that would have engendered monopoly
power was sufficient for finding of dangerous probability). Although the
dangerous probability was no longer imminent with Netscape's rejection of
Microsoft's proposal, "the probability of success at the time the acts
occur" is the measure by which liability is determined. Id. at 1118.
This conclusion alone is sufficient to support a
finding of liability for attempted monopolization. The Court is nonetheless
compelled to express its further conclusion that the predatory course of conduct
Microsoft has pursued since June of 1995 has revived the dangerous probability
that Microsoft will attain monopoly power in a second market. Internet Explorer's
share of browser usage has already risen above fifty percent, will exceed sixty
percent by January 2001, and the trend continues unabated. Findings ¶¶ 372-73;
see M&M Medical Supplies & Serv., Inc. v. Pleasant Valley
Hosp., Inc., 981 F.2d 160, 168 (4th Cir. 1992) (en banc) ("A rising
share may show more probability of success than a falling share. . . . [C]laims
involving greater than 50% share should be treated as attempts at monopolization
when the other elements for attempted monopolization are also satisfied.")
(citations omitted); see also IIIA Phillip E. Areeda & Herbert
Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 807d, at 354-55 (1996) (acknowledging the
significance of a large, rising market share to the dangerous probability
element).
II. SECTION ONE OF THE SHERMAN ACT
Section 1 of the Sherman Act prohibits "every
contract, combination . . . , or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce .
. . ." 15 U.S.C. § 1. Pursuant to this statute, courts have condemned
commercial stratagems that constitute unreasonable restraints on competition. See
Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 49 (1977); Chicago
Board of Trade v. United States, 246 U.S. 231, 238-39 (1918), among them
"tying arrangements" and "exclusive dealing" contracts.
Tying arrangements have been found unlawful where sellers exploit their market
power over one product to force unwilling buyers into acquiring another. See
Jefferson Parish Hospital District No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2, 12 (1984); Northern
Pac. Ry. Co. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1, 6 (1958); Times-Picayune Pub.
Co. v. United States, 345 U.S. 594, 605 (1953). Where agreements have been
challenged as unlawful exclusive dealing, the courts have condemned only those
contractual arrangements that substantially foreclose competition in a relevant
market by significantly reducing the number of outlets available to a competitor
to reach prospective consumers of the competitor's product. See Tampa
Electric Co. v. Nashville Coal Co., 365 U.S. 320, 327 (1961); Roland
Machinery Co. v. Dresser Industries, Inc., 749 F.2d 380, 393 (7th Cir.
1984).
A. Tying
Liability for tying under § 1 exists where (1)
two separate "products" are involved; (2) the defendant affords its
customers no choice but to take the tied product in order to obtain the tying
product; (3) the arrangement affects a substantial volume of interstate commerce;
and (4) the defendant has "market power" in the tying product market. Jefferson
Parish, 466 U.S. at 12-18. The Supreme Court has since reaffirmed this test
in Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services, Inc., 504 U.S. 451,
461-62 (1992). All four elements are required, whether the arrangement is
subjected to a per se or Rule of Reason analysis.
The plaintiffs allege that Microsoft's
combination of Windows and Internet Explorer by contractual and technological
artifices constitute unlawful tying to the extent that those actions forced
Microsoft's customers and consumers to take Internet Explorer as a condition of
obtaining Windows. While the Court agrees with plaintiffs, and thus holds that
Microsoft is liable for illegal tying under § 1, this conclusion is arguably at
variance with a decision of the U.S. Court of Appeals for the D.C. Circuit in a
closely related case, and must therefore be explained in some detail. Whether
the decisions are indeed inconsistent is not for this Court to say.
The decision of the D.C. Circuit in question is United
States v. Microsoft Corp., 147 F.3d 935 (D.C. Cir. 1998) ("Microsoft
II") which is itself related to an earlier decision of the same Circuit,
United States v. Microsoft Corp., 56 F.3d 1448 (D.C. Cir. 1995) ("Microsoft
I"). The history of the controversy is sufficiently set forth in the
appellate opinions and need not be recapitulated here, except to state that
those decisions anticipated the instant case, and that Microsoft II
sought to guide this Court, insofar as practicable, in the further proceedings
it fully expected to ensue on the tying issue. Nevertheless, upon reflection
this Court does not believe the D.C. Circuit intended Microsoft II to
state a controlling rule of law for purposes of this case. As the Microsoft
II court itself acknowledged, the issue before it was the construction to be
placed upon a single provision of a consent decree that, although animated by
antitrust considerations, was nevertheless still primarily a matter of
determining contractual intent. The court of appeals' observations on the extent
to which software product design decisions may be subject to judicial scrutiny
in the course of § 1 tying cases are in the strictest sense obiter dicta,
and are thus not formally binding. Nevertheless, both prudence and the deference
this Court owes to pronouncements of its own Circuit oblige that it follow in
the direction it is pointed until the trail falters.
The majority opinion in Microsoft II
evinces both an extraordinary degree of respect for changes (including "integration")
instigated by designers of technological products, such as software, in the name
of product "improvement," and a corresponding lack of confidence in
the ability of the courts to distinguish between improvements in fact and
improvements in name only, made for anticompetitive purposes. Read literally,
the D.C. Circuit's opinion appears to immunize any product design (or, at least,
software product design) from antitrust scrutiny, irrespective of its effect
upon competition, if the software developer can postulate any "plausible
claim" of advantage to its arrangement of code. 147 F.3d at 950.
This undemanding test appears to this Court to be
inconsistent with the pertinent Supreme Court precedents in at least three
respects. First, it views the market from the defendant's perspective, or, more
precisely, as the defendant would like to have the market viewed. Second, it
ignores reality: The claim of advantage need only be plausible; it need not be
proved. Third, it dispenses with any balancing of the hypothetical advantages
against any anticompetitive effects.
The two most recent Supreme Court cases to have
addressed the issue of product and market definition in the context of Sherman
Act tying claims are Jefferson Parish, supra, and Eastman Kodak,
supra. In Jefferson Parish, the Supreme Court held that a hospital
offering hospital services and anesthesiology services as a package could not be
found to have violated the anti-tying rules unless the evidence established that
patients, i.e. consumers, perceived the services as separate
products for which they desired a choice, and that the package had the effect of
forcing the patients to purchase an unwanted product. 466 U.S. at 21-24, 28-29.
In Eastman Kodak the Supreme Court held that a manufacturer of
photocopying and micrographic equipment, in agreeing to sell replacement parts
for its machines only to those customers who also agreed to purchase repair
services from it as well, would be guilty of tying if the evidence at trial
established the existence of consumer demand for parts and services separately.
504 U.S. at 463.
Both defendants asserted, as Microsoft does here,
that the tied and tying products were in reality only a single product, or that
every item was traded in a single market.(3) In Jefferson
Parish, the defendant contended that it offered a "functionally
integrated package of services" - a single product - but the Supreme Court
concluded that the "character of the demand" for the constituent
components, not their functional relationship, determined whether separate
"products" were actually involved. 466 U.S. at 19. In Eastman Kodak,
the defendant postulated that effective competition in the equipment market
precluded the possibility of the use of market power anticompetitively in any
after-markets for parts or services: Sales of machines, parts, and services were
all responsive to the discipline of the larger equipment market. The Supreme
Court declined to accept this premise in the absence of evidence of "actual
market realities," 504 U.S. at 466-67, ultimately holding that "the
proper market definition in this case can be determined only after a factual
inquiry into the 'commercial realities' faced by consumers." Id. at
482 (quoting United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 572 (1966)).(4)
In both Jefferson Parish and Eastman
Kodak, the Supreme Court also gave consideration to certain theoretical
"valid business reasons" proffered by the defendants as to why the
arrangements should be deemed benign. In Jefferson Parish, the hospital
asserted that the combination of hospital and anesthesia services eliminated
multiple problems of scheduling, supply, performance standards, and equipment
maintenance. 466 U.S. at 43-44. The manufacturer in Eastman Kodak
contended that quality control, inventory management, and the prevention of free
riding justified its decision to sell parts only in conjunction with service.
504 U.S. at 483. In neither case did the Supreme Court find those justifications
sufficient if anticompetitive effects were proved. Id. at 483-86; Jefferson
Parish, 466 U.S. at 25 n.42. Thus, at a minimum, the admonition of the D.C.
Circuit in Microsoft II to refrain from any product design assessment as
to whether the "integration" of Windows and Internet Explorer is a
"net plus," deferring to Microsoft's "plausible claim" that
it is of "some advantage" to consumers, is at odds with the Supreme
Court's own approach.
The significance of those cases, for this Court's
purposes, is to teach that resolution of product and market definitional
problems must depend upon proof of commercial reality, as opposed to what might
appear to be reasonable. In both cases the Supreme Court instructed that product
and market definitions were to be ascertained by reference to evidence of
consumers' perception of the nature of the products and the markets for them,
rather than to abstract or metaphysical assumptions as to the configuration of
the "product" and the "market." Jefferson Parish, 466
U.S. at 18; Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S. at 481-82. In the instant case, the
commercial reality is that consumers today perceive operating systems and
browsers as separate "products," for which there is separate demand.
Findings ¶¶ 149-54. This is true notwithstanding the fact that the software
code supplying their discrete functionalities can be commingled in virtually
infinite combinations, rendering each indistinguishable from the whole in terms
of files of code or any other taxonomy. Id. ¶¶ 149-50, 162-63, 187-91.
Proceeding in line with the Supreme Court cases,
which are indisputably controlling, this Court first concludes that Microsoft
possessed "appreciable economic power in the tying market," Eastman
Kodak, 504 U.S. at 464, which in this case is the market for
Intel-compatible PC operating systems. See Jefferson Parish, 466
U.S. at 14 (defining market power as ability to force purchaser to do something
that he would not do in competitive market); see also Fortner
Enterprises, Inc. v. United States Steel Corp., 394 U.S. 495, 504 (1969)
(ability to raise prices or to impose tie-ins on any appreciable number of
buyers within the tying product market is sufficient). While courts typically
have not specified a percentage of the market that creates the presumption of
"market power," no court has ever found that the requisite degree of
power exceeds the amount necessary for a finding of monopoly power. See Eastman
Kodak, 504 U.S. at 481. Because this Court has already found that Microsoft
possesses monopoly power in the worldwide market for Intel-compatible PC
operating systems (i.e., the tying product market), Findings ¶¶ 18-67,
the threshold element of "appreciable economic power" is a fortiori
met.
Similarly, the Court's Findings strongly support
a conclusion that a "not insubstantial" amount of commerce was
foreclosed to competitors as a result of Microsoft's decision to bundle Internet
Explorer with Windows. The controlling consideration under this element is
"simply whether a total amount of business" that is "substantial
enough in terms of dollar-volume so as not to be merely de minimis"
is foreclosed. Fortner, 394 U.S. at 501; cf. International Salt
Co. v. United States, 332 U.S. 392, 396 (1947) (unreasonable per se
to foreclose competitors from any substantial market by a tying arrangement).
Although the Court's Findings do not specify a
dollar amount of business that has been foreclosed to any particular present or
potential competitor of Microsoft in the relevant market,(5)
including Netscape, the Court did find that Microsoft's bundling practices
caused Navigator's usage share to drop substantially from 1995 to 1998, and that
as a direct result Netscape suffered a severe drop in revenues from lost
advertisers, Web traffic and purchases of server products. It is thus obvious
that the foreclosure achieved by Microsoft's refusal to offer Internet Explorer
separately from Windows exceeds the Supreme Court's de minimis
threshold. See Digidyne Corp. v. Data General Corp., 734 F.2d
1336, 1341 (9th Cir. 1984) (citing Fortner).
The facts of this case also prove the elements of
the forced bundling requirement. Indeed, the Supreme Court has stated that the
"essential characteristic" of an illegal tying arrangement is a
seller's decision to exploit its market power over the tying product "to
force the buyer into the purchase of a tied product that the buyer either did
not want at all, or might have preferred to purchase elsewhere on different
terms." Jefferson Parish, 466 U.S. at 12. In that regard, the Court
has found that, beginning with the early agreements for Windows 95, Microsoft
has conditioned the provision of a license to distribute Windows on the OEMs'
purchase of Internet Explorer. Findings ¶¶ 158-65. The agreements prohibited
the licensees from ever modifying or deleting any part of Windows, despite the
OEMs' expressed desire to be allowed to do so. Id. ¶¶ 158, 164. As a
result, OEMs were generally not permitted, with only one brief exception, to
satisfy consumer demand for a browserless version of Windows 95 without Internet
Explorer. Id. ¶¶ 158, 202. Similarly, Microsoft refused to license
Windows 98 to OEMs unless they also agreed to abstain from removing the icons
for Internet Explorer from the desktop. Id. ¶ 213. Consumers were also
effectively compelled to purchase Internet Explorer along with Windows 98 by
Microsoft's decision to stop including Internet Explorer on the list of programs
subject to the Add/Remove function and by its decision not to respect their
selection of another browser as their default. Id. ¶¶ 170-72.
The fact that Microsoft ostensibly priced
Internet Explorer at zero does not detract from the conclusion that consumers
were forced to pay, one way or another, for the browser along with Windows.
Despite Microsoft's assertion that the Internet Explorer technologies are not
"purchased" since they are included in a single royalty price paid by
OEMs for Windows 98, see Microsoft's Proposed Conclusions of Law at
12-13, it is nevertheless clear that licensees, including consumers, are forced
to take, and pay for, the entire package of software and that any value to be
ascribed to Internet Explorer is built into this single price. See United
States v. Microsoft Corp., Nos. CIV. A. 98-1232, 98-1233, 1998 WL 614485,
*12 (D.D.C., Sept. 14, 1998); IIIA Philip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust
Law ¶ 760b6, at 51 (1996) ("[T]he tie may be obvious, as in the
classic form, or somewhat more subtle, as when a machine is sold or leased at a
price that covers 'free' servicing."). Moreover, the purpose of the Supreme
Court's "forcing" inquiry is to expose those product bundles that
raise the cost or difficulty of doing business for would-be competitors to
prohibitively high levels, thereby depriving consumers of the opportunity to
evaluate a competing product on its relative merits. It is not, as Microsoft
suggests, simply to punish firms on the basis of an increment in price
attributable to the tied product. See Fortner, 394 U.S. at 512-14
(1969); Jefferson Parish, 466 U.S. at 12-13.
As for the crucial requirement that Windows and
Internet Explorer be deemed "separate products" for a finding of
technological tying liability, this Court's Findings mandate such a conclusion.
Considering the "character of demand" for the two products, as opposed
to their "functional relation," id. at 19, Web browsers and
operating systems are "distinguishable in the eyes of buyers." Id.;
Findings ¶¶ 149-54. Consumers often base their choice of which browser should
reside on their operating system on their individual demand for the specific
functionalities or characteristics of a particular browser, separate and apart
from the functionalities afforded by the operating system itself. Id.
¶¶ 149-51. Moreover, the behavior of other, lesser software vendors confirms
that it is certainly efficient to provide an operating system and a browser
separately, or at least in separable form. Id. ¶ 153. Microsoft is the
only firm to refuse to license its operating system without a browser. Id.;
see Berkey Photo, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 603 F.2d 263, 287 (2d Cir.
1979). This Court concludes that Microsoft's decision to offer only the bundled
- "integrated" - version of Windows and Internet Explorer derived not
from technical necessity or business efficiencies; rather, it was the result of
a deliberate and purposeful choice to quell incipient competition before it
reached truly minatory proportions.
The Court is fully mindful of the reasons for the
admonition of the D.C. Circuit in Microsoft II of the perils associated
with a rigid application of the traditional "separate products" test
to computer software design. Given the virtually infinite malleability of
software code, software upgrades and new application features, such as Web
browsers, could virtually always be configured so as to be capable of separate
and subsequent installation by an immediate licensee or end user. A court
mechanically applying a strict "separate demand" test could
improvidently wind up condemning "integrations" that represent genuine
improvements to software that are benign from the standpoint of consumer welfare
and a competitive market. Clearly, this is not a desirable outcome. Similar
concerns have motivated other courts, as well as the D.C. Circuit, to resist a
strict application of the "separate products" tests to similar
questions of "technological tying." See, e.g., Foremost
Pro Color, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 703 F.2d 534, 542-43 (9th Cir. 1983); Response
of Carolina, Inc. v. Leasco Response, Inc., 537 F.2d 1307, 1330 (5th Cir.
1976); Telex Corp. v. IBM Corp., 367 F. Supp. 258, 347 (N.D. Okla. 1973).
To the extent that the Supreme Court has spoken
authoritatively on these issues, however, this Court is bound to follow its
guidance and is not at liberty to extrapolate a new rule governing the tying of
software products. Nevertheless, the Court is confident that its conclusion,
limited by the unique circumstances of this case, is consistent with the Supreme
Court's teaching to date.(6)
B. Exclusive Dealing Arrangements
Microsoft's various contractual agreements with
some OLSs, ICPs, ISVs, Compaq and Apple are also called into question by
plaintiffs as exclusive dealing arrangements under the language in § 1
prohibiting "contract[s] . . . in restraint of trade or commerce . . .
." 15 U.S.C. § 1. As detailed in §I.A.2, supra, each of these
agreements with Microsoft required the other party to promote and distribute
Internet Explorer to the partial or complete exclusion of Navigator. In
exchange, Microsoft offered, to some or all of these parties, promotional
patronage, substantial financial subsidies, technical support, and other
valuable consideration. Under the clear standards established by the Supreme
Court, these types of "vertical restrictions" are subject to a Rule of
Reason analysis. See Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc.,
433 U.S. 36, 49 (1977); Jefferson Parish, 466 U.S. at 44-45 (O'Connor,
J., concurring); cf. Business Elecs. Corp. v. Sharp Elecs. Corp.,
485 U.S. 717, 724-26 (1988) (holding that Rule of Reason analysis presumptively
applies to cases brought under § 1 of the Sherman Act).
Acknowledging that some exclusive dealing
arrangements may have benign objectives and may create significant economic
benefits, see Tampa Electric Co. v. Nashville Coal Co., 365 U.S.
320, 333-35 (1961), courts have tended to condemn under the § 1 Rule of Reason
test only those agreements that have the effect of foreclosing a competing
manufacturer's brands from the relevant market. More specifically, courts are
concerned with those exclusive dealing arrangements that work to place so much
of a market's available distribution outlets in the hands of a single firm as to
make it difficult for other firms to continue to compete effectively, or even to
exist, in the relevant market. See U.S. Healthcare Inc. v.
Healthsource, Inc., 986 F.2d 589, 595 (1st Cir. 1993); Interface Group,
Inc. v. Massachusetts Port Authority, 816 F.2d 9, 11 (1st Cir. 1987)
(relying upon III Phillip E. Areeda & Donald F. Turner, Antitrust Law
¶ 732 (1978), Tampa Electric, 365 U.S. at 327-29, and Standard Oil
Co. v. United States, 337 U.S. 293 (1949)).
To evaluate an agreement's likely anticompetitive
effects, courts have consistently looked at a variety of factors, including: (1)
the degree of exclusivity and the relevant line of commerce implicated by the
agreements' terms; (2) whether the percentage of the market foreclosed by the
contracts is substantial enough to import that rivals will be largely excluded
from competition; (3) the agreements' actual anticompetitive effect in the
relevant line of commerce; (4) the existence of any legitimate, procompetitive
business justifications offered by the defendant; (5) the length and
irrevocability of the agreements; and (6) the availability of any less
restrictive means for achieving the same benefits. See, e.g., Tampa
Electric, 365 U.S. at 326-35; Roland Machinery Co. v. Dresser Industries,
Inc., 749 F.2d 380, 392-95 (7th Cir. 1984); see also XI
Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 1820 (1998).
Where courts have found that the agreements in
question failed to foreclose absolutely outlets that together accounted for a
substantial percentage of the total distribution of the relevant products, they
have consistently declined to assign liability. See, e.g., id.
¶ 1821; U.S. Healthcare, 986 F.2d at 596-97; Roland Mach. Co.,
749 F.2d at 394 (failure of plaintiff to meet threshold burden of proving that
exclusive dealing arrangement is likely to keep at least one significant
competitor from doing business in relevant market dictates no liability under §
1). This Court has previously observed that the case law suggests that, unless
the evidence demonstrates that Microsoft's agreements excluded Netscape
altogether from access to roughly forty percent of the browser market, the Court
should decline to find such agreements in violation of § 1. See United
States v. Microsoft Corp., Nos. CIV. A. 98-1232, 98-1233, 1998 WL 614485, at
*19 (D.D.C. Sept. 14, 1998) (citing cases that tended to converge upon forty
percent foreclosure rate for finding of § 1 liability).
The only agreements revealed by the evidence
which could be termed so "exclusive" as to merit scrutiny under the §
1 Rule of Reason test are the agreements Microsoft signed with Compaq, AOL and
several other OLSs, the top ICPs, the leading ISVs, and Apple. The Findings of
Fact also establish that, among the OEMs discussed supra, Compaq was the
only one to fully commit itself to Microsoft's terms for distributing and
promoting Internet Explorer to the exclusion of Navigator. Beginning with its
decisions in 1996 and 1997 to promote Internet Explorer exclusively for its PC
products, Compaq essentially ceased to distribute or pre-install Navigator at
all in exchange for significant financial remuneration from Microsoft. Findings
¶¶ 230-34. AOL's March 12 and October 28, 1996 agreements with Microsoft also
guaranteed that, for all practical purposes, Internet Explorer would be AOL's
browser of choice, to be distributed and promoted through AOL's dominant,
flagship online service, thus leaving Navigator to fend for itself. Id.
¶¶ 287-90, 293-97. In light of the severe shipment quotas and promotional
restrictions for third-party browsers imposed by the agreements, the fact that
Microsoft still permitted AOL to offer Navigator through a few subsidiary
channels does not negate this conclusion. The same conclusion as to exclusionary
effect can be drawn with respect to Microsoft's agreements with AT&T
WorldNet, Prodigy and CompuServe, since those contract terms were almost
identical to the ones contained in AOL's March 1996 agreement. Id. ¶¶
305-06.
Microsoft also successfully induced some of the
most popular ICPs and ISVs to commit to promote, distribute and utilize Internet
Explorer technologies exclusively in their Web content in exchange for valuable
placement on the Windows desktop and technical support. Specifically, the
"Top Tier" and "Platinum" agreements that Microsoft formed
with thirty-four of the most popular ICPs on the Web ensured that Navigator was
effectively shut out of these distribution outlets for a significant period of
time. Id. ¶¶ 317-22, 325-26, 332. In the same way, Microsoft's
"First Wave" contracts provided crucial technical information to
dozens of leading ISVs that agreed to make their Web-centric applications
completely reliant on technology specific to Internet Explorer. Id. ¶¶
337, 339-40. Finally, Apple's 1997 Technology Agreement with Microsoft
prohibited Apple from actively promoting any non-Microsoft browsing software in
any way or from pre-installing a browser other than Internet Explorer. Id.
¶¶ 350-52. This arrangement eliminated all meaningful avenues of distribution
of Navigator through Apple. Id.
Notwithstanding the extent to which these
"exclusive" distribution agreements preempted the most efficient
channels for Navigator to achieve browser usage share, however, the Court
concludes that Microsoft's multiple agreements with distributors did not
ultimately deprive Netscape of the ability to have access to every PC user
worldwide to offer an opportunity to install Navigator. Navigator can be
downloaded from the Internet. It is available through myriad retail channels. It
can (and has been) mailed directly to an unlimited number of households. How
precisely it managed to do so is not shown by the evidence, but in 1998 alone,
for example, Netscape was able to distribute 160 million copies of Navigator,
contributing to an increase in its installed base from 15 million in 1996 to 33
million in December 1998. Id. ¶ 378. As such, the evidence does not
support a finding that these agreements completely excluded Netscape from any
constituent portion of the worldwide browser market, the relevant line of
commerce.
The fact that Microsoft's arrangements with
various firms did not foreclose enough of the relevant market to constitute a §
1 violation in no way detracts from the Court's assignment of liability for the
same arrangements under § 2. As noted above, all of Microsoft's agreements,
including the non-exclusive ones, severely restricted Netscape's access to those
distribution channels leading most efficiently to the acquisition of browser
usage share. They thus rendered Netscape harmless as a platform threat and
preserved Microsoft's operating system monopoly, in violation of § 2. But
virtually all the leading case authority dictates that liability under § 1 must
hinge upon whether Netscape was actually shut out of the Web browser market, or
at least whether it was forced to reduce output below a subsistence level. The
fact that Netscape was not allowed access to the most direct, efficient ways to
cause the greatest number of consumers to use Navigator is legally irrelevant to
a final determination of plaintiffs' § 1 claims.
Other courts in similar contexts have declined to
find liability where alternative channels of distribution are available to the
competitor, even if those channels are not as efficient or reliable as the
channels foreclosed by the defendant. In Omega Environmental, Inc. v.
Gilbarco, Inc., 127 F.3d 1157 (9th Cir. 1997), for example, the
Ninth Circuit found that a manufacturer of petroleum dispensing equipment
"foreclosed roughly 38% of the relevant market for sales." 127 F.3d at
1162. Nonetheless, the Court refused to find the defendant liable for exclusive
dealing because "potential alternative sources of distribution"
existed for its competitors. Id. at 1163. Rejecting plaintiff's argument
(similar to the one made in this case) that these alternatives were
"inadequate substitutes for the existing distributors," the Court
stated that "[c]ompetitors are free to sell directly, to develop
alternative distributors, or to compete for the services of existing
distributors. Antitrust laws require no more." Id.; accord Seagood
Trading Corp. v. Jerrico, Inc., 924 F.2d 1555, 1572-73 (11th Cir. 1991).
III. THE STATE LAW CLAIMS
In their amended complaint, the plaintiff states
assert that the same facts establishing liability under §§ 1 and 2 of the
Sherman Act mandate a finding of liability under analogous provisions in their
own laws. The Court agrees. The facts proving that Microsoft unlawfully
maintained its monopoly power in violation of § 2 of the Sherman Act are
sufficient to meet analogous elements of causes of action arising under the laws
of each plaintiff state.(7) The Court reaches the
same conclusion with respect to the facts establishing that Microsoft attempted
to monopolize the browser market in violation of § 2,(8)
and with respect to those facts establishing that Microsoft instituted an
improper tying arrangement in violation of § 1.(9)
The plaintiff states concede that their laws do
not condemn any act proved in this case that fails to warrant liability under
the Sherman Act. States' Reply in Support of their Proposed Conclusions of Law
at 1. Accordingly, the Court concludes that, for reasons identical to those
stated in § II.B, supra, the evidence in this record does not warrant
finding Microsoft liable for exclusive dealing under the laws of any of the
plaintiff states.
Microsoft contends that a plaintiff cannot
succeed in an antitrust claim under the laws of California, Louisiana, Maryland,
New York, Ohio, or Wisconsin without proving an element that is not required
under the Sherman Act, namely, intrastate impact. Assuming that each of
those states has, indeed, expressly limited the application of its antitrust
laws to activity that has a significant, adverse effect on competition within
the state or is otherwise contrary to state interests, that element is
manifestly proven by the facts presented here. The Court has found that
Microsoft is the leading supplier of operating systems for PCs and that it
transacts business in all fifty of the United States. Findings ¶ 9.(10)
It is common and universal knowledge that millions of citizens of, and hundreds,
if not thousands, of enterprises in each of the United States and the District
of Columbia utilize PCs running on Microsoft software. It is equally clear that
certain companies that have been adversely affected by Microsoft's
anticompetitive campaign - a list that includes IBM, Hewlett-Packard, Intel,
Netscape, Sun, and many others - transact business in, and employ citizens of,
each of the plaintiff states. These facts compel the conclusion that, in each of
the plaintiff states, Microsoft's anticompetitive conduct has significantly
hampered competition.
Microsoft once again invokes the federal
Copyright Act in defending against state claims seeking to vindicate the rights
of OEMs and others to make certain modifications to Windows 95 and Windows 98.
The Court concludes that these claims do not encroach on Microsoft's federally
protected copyrights and, thus, that they are not pre-empted under the Supremacy
Clause. The Court already concluded in § I.A.2.a.i, supra, that
Microsoft's decision to bundle its browser and impose first-boot and start-up
screen restrictions constitute independent violations of § 2 of the Sherman
Act. It follows as a matter of course that the same actions merit liability
under the plaintiff states' antitrust and unfair competition laws. Indeed, the
parties agree that the standards for liability under the several plaintiff
states' antitrust and unfair competition laws are, for the purposes of this
case, identical to those expressed in the federal statute. States' Reply in
Support of their Proposed Conclusions of Law at 1; Microsoft's Sur-Reply in
Response to the States' Reply at 2 n.1. Thus, these state laws cannot
"stand[] as an obstacle to" the goals of the federal copyright law to
any greater extent than do the federal antitrust laws, for they target exactly
the same type of anticompetitive behavior. Hines v. Davidowitz, 312 U.S.
52, 67 (1941). The Copyright Act's own preemption clause provides that
"[n]othing in this title annuls or limits any rights or remedies under the
common law or statutes of any State with respect to . . . activities violating
legal or equitable rights that are not equivalent to any of the exclusive rights
within the general scope of copyright as specified by section 106 . . . ."
17 U.S.C. § 301(b)(3). Moreover, the Supreme Court has recognized that there is
"nothing either in the language of the copyright laws or in the history of
their enactment to indicate any congressional purpose to deprive the states,
either in whole or in part, of their long-recognized power to regulate
combinations in restraint of trade." Watson v. Buck, 313 U.S. 387,
404 (1941). See also Allied Artists Pictures Corp. v. Rhodes,
496 F. Supp. 408, 445 (S.D. Ohio 1980), aff'd in relevant part, 679 F.2d
656 (6th Cir. 1982) (drawing upon similarities between federal and state
antitrust laws in support of notion that authority of states to regulate market
practices dealing with copyrighted subject matter is well-established); cf.
Hines, 312 U.S. at 67 (holding state laws preempted when they
"stand[] as an obstacle to the accomplishment and execution of the full
purposes and objectives of Congress").
The Court turns finally to the counterclaim that
Microsoft brings against the attorneys general of the plaintiff states under 42
U.S.C. § 1983. In support of its claim, Microsoft argues that the attorneys
general are seeking relief on the basis of state laws, repeats its assertion
that the imposition of this relief would deprive it of rights granted to it by
the Copyright Act, and concludes with the contention that the attorneys general
are, "under color of" state law, seeking to deprive Microsoft of
rights secured by federal law - a classic violation of 42 U.S.C. § 1983.
Having already addressed the issue of whether
granting the relief sought by the attorneys general would entail conflict with
the Copyright Act, the Court rejects Microsoft's counterclaim on yet more
fundamental grounds as well: It is inconceivable that their resort to this Court
could represent an effort on the part of the attorneys general to deprive
Microsoft of rights guaranteed it under federal law, because this Court does not
possess the power to act in contravention of federal law. Therefore, since the
conduct it complains of is the pursuit of relief in federal court, Microsoft
fails to state a claim under 42 U.S.C. § 1983. Consequently, Microsoft's
request for a declaratory judgment against the states under 28 U.S.C. §§ 2201
and 2202 is denied, and the counterclaim is dismissed.
Thomas Penfield Jackson
U.S. District Judge
Date:
UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA
|
|
|
|
) |
|
| ) |
|
UNITED STATES OF AMERICA,
| ) |
|
| ) |
|
Plaintiff,
| ) |
|
| ) |
|
v.
| ) |
Civil Action No.
98-1232 (TPJ) |
| ) |
|
MICROSOFT CORPORATION,
| ) |
|
| ) |
|
Defendant.
| ) |
|
| ) |
|
|
| |
| ) |
|
STATE OF NEW YORK, et
al.,
| ) |
|
| ) |
|
Plaintiffs
| ) |
|
| ) |
|
v.
| ) |
|
| ) |
|
MICROSOFT CORPORATION,
| ) |
|
| ) |
|
Defendant
| ) |
|
| ) |
|
|
) |
Civil Action No.
98-1233 (TPJ) |
| ) |
|
MICROSOFT CORPORATION,
| ) |
|
| ) |
|
v.
| ) |
|
| ) |
|
Counterclaim-Plaintiff,
| ) |
|
| ) |
|
ELLIOT
SPITZER, attorney
| ) |
|
general of
the State of
| ) |
|
New York,
in his official
| ) |
|
capacity, et
al.,
| ) |
|
| ) |
|
Counterclaim-Defendants.
| ) |
|
| ) |
|
| |
|
ORDER
In accordance with the Conclusions
of Law filed herein this date, it is, this ______ day of April, 2000,
ORDERED, ADJUDGED, and DECLARED,
that Microsoft has violated §§ 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1,
2, as well as the following state law provisions: Cal Bus. & Prof. Code §§
16720, 16726, 17200; Conn. Gen. Stat. §§ 35-26, 35-27, 35-29; D.C. Code §§
28-4502, 28-4503; Fla. Stat. chs. 501.204(1), 542.18, 542.19; 740 Ill. Comp.
Stat. ch. 10/3; Iowa Code §§ 553.4, 553.5; Kan. Stat. §§ 50-101 et seq.;
Ky. Rev. Stat. §§ 367.170, 367.175; La. Rev. Stat. §§ 51:122, 51:123,
51:1405; Md. Com. Law II Code Ann. § 11-204; Mass. Gen. Laws ch. 93A, § 2;
Mich. Comp. Laws §§ 445.772, 445.773; Minn. Stat. § 325D.52; N.M. Stat. §§
57-1-1, 57-1-2; N.Y. Gen. Bus. Law § 340; N.C. Gen. Stat. §§ 75-1.1, 75-2.1;
Ohio Rev. Code §§ 1331.01, 1331.02; Utah Code § 76-10-914; W.Va. Code §§
47-18-3, 47-18-4; Wis. Stat. § 133.03(1)-(2); and it is
FURTHER ORDERED, that judgment is
entered for the United States on its second, third, and fourth claims for relief
in Civil Action No. 98-1232; and it is
FURTHER ORDERED, that the first
claim for relief in Civil Action No. 98-1232 is dismissed with prejudice; and it
is
FURTHER ORDERED, that judgment is
entered for the plaintiff states on their first, second, fourth, sixth, seventh,
eighth, ninth, tenth, eleventh, twelfth, thirteenth, fourteenth, fifteenth,
sixteenth, seventeenth, eighteenth, nineteenth, twentieth, twenty-first,
twenty-second, twenty-fourth, twenty-fifth, and twenty-sixth claims for relief
in Civil Action No. 98-1233; and it is
FURTHER ORDERED, that the fifth
claim for relief in Civil Action No. 98-1233 is dismissed with prejudice; and it
is
FURTHER ORDERED, that Microsoft's
first and second claims for relief in Civil Action No. 98-1233 are dismissed
with prejudice; and it is
FURTHER ORDERED, that the Court
shall, in accordance with the Conclusions of Law filed herein, enter an Order
with respect to appropriate relief, including an award of costs and fees,
following proceedings to be established by further Order of the Court.
Thomas Penfield Jackson
U.S. District Judge
1. Proof that the
defendant's conduct was motivated by a desire to prevent other firms from
competing on the merits can contribute to a finding that the conduct has had, or
will have, the intended, exclusionary effect. See United States v.
United States Gypsum Co., 438 U.S. 422, 436 n.13 (1978) ("consideration
of intent may play an important role in divining the actual nature and effect of
the alleged anticompetitive conduct").
2. While
Microsoft is correct that some courts have also recognized the right of a
copyright holder to preserve the "integrity" of artistic works in
addition to those rights enumerated in the Copyright Act, the Court nevertheless
concludes that those cases, being actions for infringement without antitrust
implications, are inapposite to the one currently before it. See, e.g.,
WGN Continental Broadcasting Co. v. United Video, Inc., 693 F.2d 622 (7th
Cir. 1982); Gilliam v. ABC, Inc., 538 F.2d 14 (2d Cir. 1976).
3. Microsoft
contends that Windows and Internet Explorer represent a single "integrated
product," and that the relevant market is a unitary market of "platforms
for software applications." Microsoft's Proposed Conclusions of Law at 49
n.28.
4. In Microsoft
II the D.C. Circuit acknowledged it was without benefit of a complete
factual record which might alter its conclusion that the "Windows 95/IE
package is a genuine integration." 147 F.3d at 952.
5. Most of the
quantitative evidence was presented in units other than monetary, but numbered
the units in millions, whatever their nature.
6. Amicus curiae
Lawrence Lessig has suggested that a corollary concept relating to the bundling
of "partial substitutes" in the context of software design may be
apposite as a limiting principle for courts called upon to assess the compliance
of these products with antitrust law. This Court has been at pains to point out
that the true source of the threat posed to the competitive process by
Microsoft's bundling decisions stems from the fact that a competitor to the tied
product bore the potential, but had not yet matured sufficiently, to open up the
tying product market to competition. Under these conditions, the anticompetitive
harm from a software bundle is much more substantial and pernicious than the
typical tie. See X Phillip E. Areeda, Einer Elhauge & Herbert
Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶1747 (1996). A company able to leverage its
substantial power in the tying product market in order to force consumers to
accept a tie of partial substitutes is thus able to spread inefficiency from one
market to the next, id. at 232, and thereby "sabotage a nascent
technology that might compete with the tying product but for its foreclosure
from the market." III Phillip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust
Law ¶ 1746.1d at 495 (Supp. 1999).
7. See
Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code §§ 16720, 16726, 17200 (West 1999); Conn. Gen. Stat.
§ 35-27 (1999); D.C. Code § 28-4503 (1996); Fla. Stat. chs. 501.204(1), 542.19
(1999); 740 Ill. Comp. Stat. 10/3 (West 1999); Iowa Code § 553.5 (1997); Kan.
Stat. §§ 50-101 et seq. (1994); Ky. Rev. Stat. §§ 367.170, 367.175 (Michie
1996); La. Rev. Stat. §§ 51:123, 51:1405 (West 1986); Md. Com. Law II Code Ann.
§ 11-204 (1990); Mass. Gen. Laws ch. 93A, § 2; Mich. Comp. Laws § 445.773
(1989); Minn. Stat. § 325D.52 (1998); N.M. Stat. § 57-1-2 (Michie 1995); N.Y.
Gen. Bus. Law § 340 (McKinney 1998); N.C. Gen. Stat. §§ 75-1.1, 75-2.1
(1999); Ohio Rev. Code §§ 1331.01, 1331.02 (Anderson 1993); Utah Code §
76-10-914 (1999); W.Va. Code § 47-18-4 (1999); Wis. Stat. § 133.03(2) (West
1989 & Supp. 1998).
8. See
Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code § 17200 (West 1999); Conn. Gen. Stat. § 35-27
(1999); D.C. Code § 28-4503 (1996); Fla. Stat. chs. 501.204(1), 542.19 (1999);
740 Ill. Comp. Stat. 10/3(3) (West 1999); Iowa Code § 553.5 (1997); Kan. Stat.
§§ 50-101 et seq. (1994); Ky. Rev. Stat. §§ 367.170, 367.175 (Michie
1996); La. Rev. Stat. §§ 51:123, 51:1405 (West 1986); Md. Com. Law II Code Ann.
§ 11-204(a)(2) (1990); Mass. Gen. Laws ch. 93A, § 2; Mich. Comp. Laws §
445.773 (1989); Minn. Stat. § 325D.52 (1998); N.M. Stat. § 57-1-2 (Michie
1995); N.Y. Gen. Bus. Law § 340 (McKinney 1988); N.C. Gen. Stat. §§ 75-1.1,
75-2.1 (1999); Ohio Rev. Code §§ 1331.01, 1331.02 (Anderson 1993); Utah Code
§ 76-10-914 (1999); W.Va. Code § 47-18-4 (1999); Wis. Stat. § 133.03(2) (West
1989 & Supp. 1998).
9. See
Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code §§ 16727, 17200 (West 1999); Conn. Gen. Stat. §§
35-26, 35-29 (1999); D.C. Code § 28-4502 (1996); Fla. Stat. chs. 501.204(1),
542.18 (1999); 740 Ill. Comp. Stat. 10/3(4) (West 1999); Iowa Code § 553.4
(1997); Kan. Stat. §§ 50-101 et seq. (1994); Ky. Rev. Stat. §§
367.170, 367.175 (Michie 1996); La. Rev. Stat. §§ 51:122, 51:1405 (West 1986);
Md. Com. Law II Code Ann. § 11-204(a)(1) (1990); Mass. Gen. Laws ch. 93A, § 2;
Mich. Comp. Laws § 445.772 (1989); Minn. Stat. § 325D.52 (1998); N.M. Stat. §
57-1-1 (Michie 1995); N.Y. Gen. Bus. Law § 340 (McKinney 1988); N.C. Gen. Stat.
§§ 75-1.1, 75-2.1 (1999); Ohio Rev. Code §§ 1331.01, 1331.02 (Anderson
1993); Utah Code § 76-10-914 (1999); W.Va. Code § 47-18-3 (1999); Wis. Stat.
§ 133.03(1) (West 1989 & Supp. 1998).
10. The omission
of the District of Columbia from this finding was an oversight on the part of
the Court; Microsoft obviously conducts business in the District of Columbia as
well. |